The Case for a Hard Break With China

Oren Cass, Gabriela Rodriguez July 25, 2023 - Globalization

Why Economic De-Risking Is Not Enough

Recommended Reading
The Case for a Hard Break With China
Policy Brief: End “Permanent Normal Trade Relations” with China
Only Trump Could Confront China

Never in human history have nations with such radically different economic and political systems as the United States and China attempted economic integration. Before the modern era, neither the markets nor the technology existed to facilitate such a project. During the Cold War, facing similar differences, Washington and Moscow stayed economically far apart. PepsiCo’s opening of a Soviet bottling plant was front-page news in 1972, and because rubles were not convertible to dollars, the Soviets paid for the bottling equipment with vodka. No wonder that globalization gained steam only after the Berlin Wall fell.

In the early post–Cold War years, U.S. theorists and policymakers ignored the potential risks of integration with an authoritarian peer. Globalization was predicated on liberal economic standards, democratic values, and U.S. cultural norms, all of which were taken for granted by economists and the foreign policy establishment. The United States set the rules for international institutions and multinational corporations, most of which were either American or heavily reliant upon access to U.S. technology and markets. Under these conditions, economic entanglements were regarded as opportunities for Washington to exert leverage and impose its rules. Incursions in, and distortions of, one market by another were Washington’s strategy, not its problem.

When welcomed into the international community in the late 1990s, China was still a developing nation. Its GDP was roughly one-tenth of the United States’ GDP, and in 1999, it was still one of the world’s poorest countries per capita, ranked between Sri Lanka and Guyana. U.S. leaders across the political spectrum were confident that by encouraging China’s integration into the global economy, they could ensure that the country would become a constructive participant in a U.S.-led world order. U.S. President Bill Clinton spoke for many when he declared that China’s accession to the World Trade Organization was about “more than our economic interests; it is clearly in our larger national interest.”

It has not turned out that way. Instead, China has rapidly become—by some measures— the world’s largest economy and a powerful counterweight to U.S. influence. Its state-controlled economy and increasingly authoritarian leadership have subverted U.S. investment, supply chains, and institutions. Beijing’s efforts to use global integration to enhance Chinese power and harm U.S. interests have proliferated. The Chinese government has leveraged market access to force technology transfers from U.S. firms including Westinghouse, General Electric, and Microsoft. It has dominated global markets by flooding them with subsidized goods, including solar panels, and it has forced the National Basketball Association and its players into humiliating silence on Chinese human rights abuses.

The fundamental problem is that the United States’ free-market economy is incompatible with a Chinese state-controlled one. U.S. liberty and democracy are antithetical to the authoritarianism of the Chinese Communist Party. The United States must break from China or else become irrevocably corrupted by it.

Continue reading in Foreign Affairs
Oren Cass
Oren Cass is the executive director at American Compass.
@oren_cass
Gabriela Rodriguez
Gabriela Rodriguez is a policy advisor at American Compass.
@gnrodriguez2
Recommended Reading
The Case for a Hard Break With China

In Foreign Affairs, Oren Cass and Gabriela Rodriguez make the case for why economic de-risking is ot Enough

Policy Brief: End “Permanent Normal Trade Relations” with China

Reclaiming control of U.S. trade policy

Only Trump Could Confront China

The inside story of the trade negotiation that changed the world

Only Trump Could Confront China

Robert Lighthizer June 30, 2023 - Globalization

The inside story of the trade negotiation that changed the world

RECOMMENDED READING
The Case for a Hard Break With China
Policy Brief: End “Permanent Normal Trade Relations” with China
Bad Trade

Adapted from the new book, No Trade Is Free: Changing Course, Taking on China, and Helping America’s Workers.

On November 9, 2017, the American state car, known as “the Beast,” bearing President Trump rolled through Beijing into Tiananmen Square. It was the first official visit of his administration to China. In front of the Great Hall of the People, the red carpet had been literally rolled out for the president and his delegation to which I, as the United States Trade Representative (USTR), belonged.

Chinese officials were very much aware of the positions Trump had taken in his campaign and had set about to charm him by engineering a visit to Mar-a-Lago in Palm Beach in April, right after his inauguration. That visit—with its memorable images of the president’s granddaughter singing a song in Mandarin to the smiling Chinese president and his wife—had succeeded in getting the two leaders off on the right foot. China’s early charm offensive at Mar-a-Lago continued in full force when we arrived in Beijing. In an unprecedented move, President Xi and his wife had given President Trump and Melania a personal tour of the Forbidden City—the vast palace complex that is the ancient seat of Chinese emperors.

The next day, the official meetings began. I found myself sitting in a cavernous room under a crystal chandelier that was perhaps ten feet in diameter. The American and Chinese delegations faced each other in two parallel lines across a gleaming conference table of heroic proportions. At the center of one side was President Xi. On the other side, facing him, sat President Trump with his 12 senior officials. President Trump was flanked by Secretary of State Rex Tillerson and our ambassador to China, former Iowa governor Terry Branstad. I sat next to Tillerson. Despite the warmth of the welcoming ceremonies, this was essentially a meeting between the leading ranks of two armies facing off against each other. As with all such occasions, the opening comments were highly scripted, with the wording having been hammered out in conference with staff and the implications of each phrase carefully weighed in advance.

President Xi read his formal statement, followed by President Trump. Both statements were cordial, raising issues only in the most diplomatic of terms. After that, President Xi called on his foreign minister to make a statement on foreign policy issues. Following protocol, President Trump did the same thing and called on Secretary Tillerson. Then came the curve ball.

I talked about the theft of technology, the failure to protect intellectual property, cyber theft, the lack of progress in the multitude of talks held over the course of the previous two administrations, and the stream of gigantic trade deficits.

Following a short statement on economic issues, President Trump looked briefly in my direction and called on me to speak to the Chinese about our position on trade. I had no carefully scripted statement. For the next several minutes, in a very respectful but direct way, I explained to the Chinese leadership our thoughts on the current trade situation. I talked about the theft of technology, the failure to protect intellectual property, cyber theft, the lack of progress in the multitude of talks held over the course of the previous two administrations, and the stream of gigantic trade deficits. I tried to explain all of this from our perspective, how the American people viewed our economic relationship as an uneven, unfair one that wasn’t sustainable and how it had affected people’s lives in many communities.

The Chinese appeared surprised by my statement. There was a pause. The group grappled with an appropriate response to an outbreak of candor in the midst of a highly choreographed meeting. As if by some silent consensus, their delegation then continued to read the rest of their formal statements.

Opening Moves

By this time, we were three months into the process of rebalancing a trading relationship that had gone catastrophically awry over the prior two decades. The U.S. decision to grant China Permanent Normal Trading Relations (PNTR) and support its ascension to the World Trade Organization (WTO) in 2001 had been a fundamental error that allowed China to seize leadership in vital industries while hollowing out American manufacturing. Under PNTR, the United States committed to offering China our most favorable trade terms, in perpetuity, removing much of the leverage that we could otherwise exercise in attempting to maintain a level playing field for trade with China.

The WTO, instead, would now enforce the rules. But working through its official channels brought frustration to a fine art and its arcane rules structured any complaints in very specific terms that precluded addressing problems at the level of their root causes. Even when the WTO chose to act in our favor, there was no effective means to enforce compliance.

If we wanted to confront China’s abuses, the United States had no choice but to act on its own. But how could we find room to move within the strictures of U.S. law? My solution to this problem lay in the revitalization of a legal tool called Section 301. This provision of the Trade Act of 1974 states that if there is an “act, policy or practice” of a foreign government that is “unreasonable or discriminatory” and “burdens or restricts U.S. commerce,” the president, acting through the USTR, can take “all appropriate and feasible action” to counteract that policy. This includes placing tariffs and restrictions on products imported into the United States.

Section 301 has been used several times over the years, mostly to give some teeth to trade negotiations. I constantly had it on my desk during my time as deputy USTR in the Reagan administration, and when negotiations with South Korea over carbon steel stalled in 1984, I threatened to go to the president and ask for authority to bring a Section 301 case, which could have ended their access to the U.S. market. This move was effective—we ended up making a deal. Later, the Clinton administration used Section 301 in a similar way, as leverage in negotiations with Japan on auto trade.

No president had ever attempted to use this authority to broadly attack massive and damaging unfair practices like China’s. No one had ever used it to impose large tariffs on a trading partner. This powerful tool was just sitting on the shelf.

I had long believed that putting appropriate tariffs on Chinese imports to the United States was the only feasible way to address China’s systemic mercantilist practices. I proposed to President Trump that we revitalize Section 301 for this purpose, as well as to make maximum use of the powers that it gave the president to exert leverage in negotiations. No president had ever attempted to use this authority to broadly attack massive and damaging unfair practices like China’s. No one had ever used it to impose large tariffs on a trading partner. This powerful tool was just sitting on the shelf.

On August 14, 2017, in the White House diplomatic reception room that once hosted Franklin Roosevelt’s fireside chats, President Trump put the tool to work. He signed an order that authorized me as USTR to begin an investigation of China’s practices on forced technology transfers, intellectual property protection, and cyber theft. The seven-month investigation was conducted by USTR staff with support from across the federal government and concluded with the release on March 22, 2018, of a historic 200-page report carefully demonstrating the many abuses in China’s technology transfer regime, its licensing restrictions for U.S. businesses, its state-sponsored investments to acquire U.S. technologies, and its repeated attacks on our commercial computer networks.

Less than two weeks later, on April 3, we announced $50 billion worth of Chinese imports that would be subject to 25% tariffs pursuant to the Section 301 action. Sectors including aerospace, information and communication technology, robotics, and machinery were selected through an extensive interagency economic analysis with the goal of having those goods that benefited from China’s policies pay the price. Within a day, China retaliated with a list of $50 billion of U.S. imports that would be subject to 25% tariffs.

While Steven Mnuchin, Secretary of the Treasury, wanted to find a negotiated solution to prevent the 25% tariffs from taking effect, I firmly believed that the tariffs were a necessary, appropriate, and measured step. The president was on my side and constantly resolute. Secretary Mnuchin and I sent a letter to Chinese Vice Premier Liu He on April 20, setting forth the broad outlines of an agreement to resolve outstanding issues between our two countries. We also agreed to travel to Beijing for talks.

Vice Premier Liu would be my counterpart for the remainder of the Trump administration. He had earned degrees in economics from Renmin University, China’s most prestigious in that field, and also a master’s degree in public policy from Harvard University. He handled difficult situations well and could argue his position without relying on talking points. He and his immediate team understood the issues. They spoke English and were familiar with Western history and philosophy. He proved to be a tough and very smart negotiator but always an honorable man. I came to admire him.

On May 3 and 4 in Beijing, Vice Premier Liu’s delegation met with ours, which consisted of myself, Secretary Mnuchin, Secretary Wilbur Ross, Larry Kudlow, and Peter Navarro; Mnuchin was the designated lead. China tested our group’s mettle and unity by proposing an “early harvest agreement”—that is, a partial agreement that would relieve pressure on the Chinese and lift some of the tariffs. This would be like the dialogues of the past where they strung us along. Peter Navarro and I strongly opposed any early harvest. We thought it would reduce our leverage and make it much harder to make any real progress.

Later in May, the vice premier and his delegation came to Washington for three days of meetings. Once again, the Chinese pursued an early harvest deal addressing purchases and issues on which China had previously made and failed to fulfill commitments. Secretary Mnuchin continued ostensibly to serve as the lead for our side, but he was less concerned with structural issues causing the distortions and unsustainable imbalance in our trade relationship with China. I had to fight to keep the focus on the major structural issues and not have our side settle on an agreement covering some “old wine in new bottles” and a commitment to purchase more U.S. exports.

The fact that we had not reached any type of real agreement was fine with me. In fact, I was thrilled that there was no deal that would prevent us from moving forward with the tariffs.

At the conclusion of the meetings in Washington, on May 19, the two sides issued a joint statement that was short on specific commitments and focused far more than I would have preferred on purchases. It provided that “China will significantly increase purchases of United States goods and services” and that the two sides “agreed on meaningful increases in United States agriculture and energy exports.” The fact that we had not reached any type of real agreement was fine with me. In fact, I was thrilled that there was no deal that would prevent us from moving forward with the tariffs.

Secretary Mnuchin had a different take. He went on one of the Sunday talk shows and claimed that the tariffs were “on hold.” I spoke to the president, who was in his White House residence, over the phone, to emphasize that staying on track with the imposition of the tariffs was the only way to gain the leverage necessary to get a good deal with the Chinese. He was completely supportive. I released a statement indicating that “the United States may use all of its legal tools to protect our technology through tariffs, investment restrictions and export regulations.” I added, “Real structural change is necessary. Nothing less than the future of tens of millions of American jobs is at stake.” And on May 29, the White House released a statement saying that we would impose tariffs on $50 billion in goods from China in June.

On June 15, incorporating public comments on how best to minimize the pain felt by U.S. companies and consumers while most directly targeting China’s “Made in China 2025” industrial policy, we announced the final list of products—two lists, actually, that would be subject to the tariffs beginning at different times. “List 1” covered $34 billion of Chinese products; “List 2” covered an additional $16 billion. We had shown restraint in imposing tariffs on only $50 billion of China’s imports, but no administration had ever stood up to them before, and I’m sure they were confident that we would back down. I always assumed that all the lobbyists and former government officials opposing our actions believed this, too. Thus, rather than address any of our concerns, China immediately published its own two-phase list of retaliatory tariffs.

They had not faced Trump and this new team, so they didn’t fully know who they were dealing with. It was one of many serious miscalculations the Chinese would make in our trade dispute. On June 18, as a response to China’s failure to change its unfair trade practices and its decision instead to pursue unlawful retaliation that could result in additional harm to the U.S. economy, the president directed me to identify another $200 billion worth of Chinese goods (“List 3”) on which to impose a 10% tariff. These numbers were far from arbitrary. We had taken the position that the initial $50 billion figure was roughly comparable to the costs that China’s unfair practices imposed on our economy. Now, China’s $50 billion in retaliatory tariffs covered 40% of our total exports to them. Our $200 billion in new tariffs would in turn cover 40% of their $500 billion in exports to us.

The Chinese had overplayed their hand, and we were using the imbalanced trading relationship that they had created against them.

Our first 25% tariffs went into effect on July 6 for the $34 billion of Chinese goods on List 1 and then on August 23 for the $16 billion on List 2. Each time, China’s retaliation of 25% tariffs on the same value of U.S. goods became effective the same day. Thus far, the Chinese had been matching us dollar for dollar with their retaliatory tariffs. But they had a problem: tariffs on the $200 billion of additional Chinese goods on List 3 were on the way; they only had about $60 billion in U.S. goods left to hit. The Chinese had overplayed their hand, and we were using the imbalanced trading relationship that they had created against them. In response to our proposed tariffs on $200 billion of additional Chinese goods, China announced its intent to impose tariffs on the remaining $60 billion of U.S. goods. They were out of ammunition.

With China still refusing to change its harmful behavior, and given its ongoing illegal retaliation, the president directed USTR to consider increasing the proposed tariff on the next $200 billion of List 3 Chinese goods from 10% to 25%. We decided to move forward with the 10% tariff on September 24 and announce a planned increase to 25% on January 1, 2019, which would give us additional leverage in the negotiations.

The looming deadline had its desired effect and China finally began discussing the structural issues that we had been raising regarding forced technology transfer, intellectual property, non-tariff barriers, services market access, and agricultural market access. China identified 142 separate issues that we had raised and, in early November, they presented a series of non-papers (unofficial diplomatic notes) sorting the issues into three categories: “green light” issues on which they believed we could reach agreement if we “met each other halfway,” “yellow light” issues on which they believed we could have “in-depth discussions” and potentially reach agreement, and “red light” issues where they believed no agreement would be possible.

As the Chinese peppered us with additional non-papers explaining their classification of each issue, it became clear that they continued to misjudge our side and overplay their hand. They believed we could reach agreement on the “green light” issues only because they thought that actions China had already taken or was planning to take would be sufficient. We had to explain repeatedly that if the actions China had taken or was planning to take were sufficient, we would not be raising the issues with them in the first place. In addition, China classified the most important issues as “red light” ones, which ensured that no progress could be made.

The Chinese still wanted a deal focused on increasing purchases of U.S. goods. Their proposal seemed unrealistic, unenforceable, and insufficient.

One month before the List 3 deadline, on December 1, President Trump and President Xi met at the G20 summit in Buenos Aires for a working dinner. In addition to the president, the U.S. delegation for the meeting included Secretary Mnuchin, Secretary of State Mike Pompeo, National Security Advisor John Bolton, Peter Navarro, Jared Kushner, Larry Kudlow, and me. By now the president had decided that I should head the U.S. delegation in the negotiations. Secretary Mnuchin and I had met with Vice Premier Liu the prior day to review the latest numbers, a framework and agenda for the meeting, and potential outcomes. The Chinese still wanted a deal focused on increasing purchases of U.S. goods. Their proposal seemed unrealistic, unenforceable, and insufficient.

The dinner lasted about two-and-a-half hours. It began with President Xi making a long, prepared statement mostly focused on trade. He also addressed the Chinese government preventing certain dual Chinese-U.S. citizens from leaving China, fentanyl, and North Korea. President Trump then made his own statement, cordial but businesslike. On trade, President Trump provided an overview of our concerns and then turned it over to me. While respectful in addressing President Xi and his senior delegation, I provided a blunt and frank assessment of where we were in our dispute: the massive distortions in the trade relationship caused by China’s unfair trade practices; the egregious harm that our workers, farmers, manufacturers, and other businesses had suffered as a result; and the absence of progress on these matters over the years of our talks.

Coming into the dinner, we had all known that China would seek a removal of the tariffs we had imposed, or at least the tariffs on $200 billion of List 3 Chinese goods, so it was no surprise when China made this request. To address our concern about the enormous trade imbalance between our two countries, President Xi offered to have China increase purchases of U.S. goods and services by $1.2 trillion over six years. I had met previously with the president to explain why purchases were inadequate, the importance of focusing on structural issues, and the need to maintain tariffs already in place until structural issues were resolved.

As he so often did during these times, the president held firm. The tariffs stayed. We did agree to postpone the tariff increase scheduled for January 1, 2019 until March 1, while China committed to a substantial increase in the purchase of additional U.S. goods and services of all types and, most importantly, to begin immediately with negotiations on the full range of structural issues. If no agreement was reached on these issues by March 1, we would raise the List 3 tariffs from 10% to 25%. In other words, we had 90 days.

Stalemate

As I recounted, Confucius said, “In the past, when I evaluated a person, I believed what they said. Now, when I evaluate a person, I listen to them and then I see what they do.”

After a series of preliminary discussions, we held the first formal principal-level meetings on January 30 and 31, 2019. The U.S. delegation included me, Secretary Mnuchin, Secretary Ross, Peter Navarro, and Larry Kudlow. In my opening statement, I once again highlighted certain key themes and offered a quote from Confucius that I thought was particularly apt for our talks. As I recounted, Confucius said, “In the past, when I evaluated a person, I believed what they said. Now, when I evaluate a person, I listen to them and then I see what they do.” This was critical for us, I explained; we had to have a strong and clear path for enforcement in any agreement we reached. 

Vice Premier Liu and I spent most of our time over the next two days discussing forced technology transfer, intellectual property, and enforcement. I raised China’s joint venture requirements, ownership restrictions, and administrative licensing and approval processes that pressured U.S. companies to transfer their technology to Chinese companies. I also addressed China’s discriminatory intellectual property licensing regulations and its state-led investment in high-tech sectors. While we made some progress in these areas, issues such as state-sponsored cyber intrusions and cyber theft proved more difficult.

On enforcement, Vice Premier Liu seemed to understand our concerns, but his first suggestion was unsatisfactory. He provided a rough outline for an enforcement process that relied heavily on discussions between the parties. In response, I told him that while process and discussions were important, the two keys to any mechanism would be who determines whether there is a breach of the agreement and what the consequences are when there is a breach. When the vice premier suggested the use of a dispute settlement panel process such as that provided for under the United States–Mexico–Canada Agreement (USMCA), I was quick to note that the United States would want, at least in certain cases, to make its own decision on compliance and remedies, rather than have those decisions made by a panel. It seemed impossible that truly neutral Chinese arbitrators could be found, and the idea of using third-country judges was out of the question for both the United States and China.

It was important for us that we see some evidence of China’s good-faith intent to actually implement suggested changes, given their history of reneging on commitments. We were giving them an opportunity to prove it.

Toward the end of the meetings on January 31, we submitted a list of actions that could and, we believed, should be taken immediately by China. It was important for us that we see some evidence of China’s good-faith intent to actually implement suggested changes, given their history of reneging on commitments. We were giving them an opportunity to prove it. These immediate actions ranged from China lifting its foreign investment restrictions to eliminating its discriminatory intellectual property licensing regulations to granting approvals for U.S. companies seeking to provide credit rating, electronic payment, and insurance services in China. Vice Premier Liu responded favorably to certain of these items but said China would respond formally at a later date.

On February 8, we delivered three memorandums of understanding (MOUs) to the Chinese side, covering forced technology transfer, intellectual property, and agricultural barriers and market access. It quickly became clear that there was backsliding by China in a number of areas from where we had been in our meetings in Washington. This was a major problem and exactly where I started in our next principal-level meeting. I expressed that we had great confidence in Vice Premier Liu but that we were discouraged by China’s backsliding. Noting China’s history of unkept promises, I emphasized the great risk if we reverted to prior failed efforts. The vice premier assured us that this time was different and that the Chinese would do everything that he promised without any changes. Unfortunately, issues with backsliding by China would be a recurring theme.

Although I could not definitively know what was going on behind the scenes in China, I was sure that Vice Premier Liu was dealing with multiple, interrelated tensions within the Chinese political system as he syndicated our proposed agreements. Beyond pushback from Chinese Communist Party (CCP) hardliners, who opposed market-oriented reforms or concessions to American demands instinctively, he also faced tensions from China’s entrenched administrative bureaucracy, which feared losing control and discretion over important policy areas. He also had to navigate long-standing divisions between the provincial and national governments in China, as many provincial leaders staunchly opposed concessions by the national government that would limit their ability to control local economic policy. Finally, he faced difficulties when agreeing to changes to policy areas outside of his direct portfolio of responsibilities separate from his (temporary) role as the chief negotiator—we often saw that the negotiations were most productive when discussing matters that the vice premier could implement himself. The vice premier surely kept President Xi continuously apprised of our discussions, but negotiated concessions continually disappeared or reemerged in watered-down form as the details spread to different interest groups within the Chinese government and Chinese leaders responded to consequent internal pressures.

[N]egotiated concessions continually disappeared or reemerged in watered-down form as the details spread to different interest groups within the Chinese government and Chinese leaders responded to consequent internal pressures.

Our discussions then moved to areas that we had not reached in our meetings in Washington, such as barriers to services and agriculture trade and, importantly, China’s massive subsidies that provide an unfair advantage to its own companies, its enormous excess capacity in industries such as steel and aluminum, needed disciplines on its State-Owned Enterprises (SOEs), its “secure and controllable” policies for information and communication technology, and the use of its anti-monopoly law. Vice Premier Liu recognized the importance of eliminating subsidies and excess capacity and sought only to carve out subsidies for laid-off employees. He also expressed openness to strong disciplines on SOEs and to SOE reform, which was another area within his portfolio.

On the evening of February 14, we had dinner at the Beijing Hotel with the Chinese delegation. The Beijing Hotel had great symbolic significance for relations between the United States and China because it served as one of the locations where Henry Kissinger and Zhou Enlai met in 1971 before President Nixon’s visit to China the following year. The hotel overlooks the Forbidden City and has views of Tiananmen Square. At the conclusion of this trip to Beijing, Secretary Mnuchin and I and a few other members of our delegation were invited to meet with President Xi in the Great Hall of the People.

Unfortunately, when we hosted the next set of meetings in Washington on February 21, the Chinese side attempted to change language in the MOUs that represented commitments made by Vice Premier Liu in Beijing. This backtracking necessitated that I go through each of the MOUs with the vice premier, provision by provision, to nail down the language. In doing so, I had to explain the basis and justification for each of the provisions and the language used. It was again clear what was happening. The vice premier would act in good faith in our talks, but when word got back to other power sources in Beijing, there would be blowback.

Although the process of going through each provision line by line required much time and painstaking effort, it was essential and resulted in our making a great deal of headway. To take advantage of the momentum, we extended the two-day talks through the weekend. Key progress was made on issues across the MOUs on forced technology transfer, intellectual property, non-tariff measures, services, agriculture, and currency. Even on seemingly intractable problems such as industrial subsidies, excess capacity, and SOEs, China was willing to agree to critical disciplines. We had a lengthy discussion on what would happen with the tariffs if we were to reach an agreement. I explained that the 25% tariffs on the $50 billion of List 1 and 2 Chinese goods would remain in effect for the long term and that the 10% tariffs on the $200 billion of List 3 Chinese goods would remain in effect initially but could be reduced over time as China implemented its commitments under the agreement. It was clear that the removal of the tariffs represented a core issue for China.

President Trump was a hands-on boss. He was constantly involved in the details of our negotiations. For me that was a great way to work. I always knew I was precisely representing his position and that he would back me up.

After the conclusion of our meetings on February 24, Secretary Mnuchin and I briefed the president in detail on the status of the talks. President Trump was a hands-on boss. He was constantly involved in the details of our negotiations. For me that was a great way to work. I always knew I was precisely representing his position and that he would back me up.Given the progress we had made, the president decided to postpone the tariff increase on the $200 billion of List 3 Chinese goods scheduled for March 1. We would have more time to talk.

At this point in the negotiations, there were regular, ongoing exchanges of text between the parties. Despite the substantial progress in our meetings in Washington, the consensus we reached on a number of key issues was not reflected in the text we received from China. For issues on which we thought we had reached agreement, it started to appear as though we had not. Further, China tried to bilateralize commitments to make them applicable to both the United States and China where it was not possible or appropriate to do so, including for China-specific issues. In some cases, as in the intellectual property and agriculture chapters, China sent us entirely new, U.S.-only commitments. Once again, I suspected the Chinese hawks and bureaucrats were undercutting their negotiator.

I had no interest in any kind of ambiguity—constructive or otherwise.

On March 6, we had the first of a series of conference calls with Vice Premier Liu and his team. At one point, he suggested that we could follow the approach of the Shanghai CommuniquĂ©, the famous document issued by the United States and China during President Nixon’s visit to China in 1972 to normalize relations. The Shanghai CommuniquĂ© reviewed the differences between the two countries and then expressed their mutual interests. It used what is called “constructive ambiguity.” This was not the first—and would not be the last—time that the Chinese mentioned following this approach. I rejected this idea. I had no interest in any kind of ambiguity—constructive or otherwise.

Over the course of these calls, the negotiations had progressed sufficiently that we talked at various times about a potential meeting or telephone call between President Trump and President Xi to conclude an agreement. We continued to discuss the language of the agreement line by line—my negotiation binders were beginning to have more lines and written notes in multicolor than print on the pages.

We held meetings in Beijing on March 28 and in Washington the following week, which represented the eighth and ninth rounds of negotiations. We continued to make steady progress on the text in a series of conference calls throughout the month of April and then met in Beijing on April 30. At this point I conveyed that we had this round and the next round to complete the agreement and that we needed to decide whether or not we would have a deal. If not, President Trump would move forward with additional tariffs on Chinese goods.

What we heard from Vice Premier Liu was highly discouraging. He explained that the Chinese needed the complete removal of all tariffs and additional changes to the structure of the text to make it more balanced. But even more significantly and troublingly, the political leadership in China had strong objections to specific structural changes provided for in the agreed text. They contended that it would look as if China’s sovereignty and dignity were being undermined and as if the United States were imposing another unfair treaty on China.

I explained that we were very much aware of the history of unfair agreements for China, including those from the Opium Wars through the Japanese occupation of China. But this situation, I argued, was the exact opposite. How could China feel aggrieved when it had accumulated over a trillion dollars in trade surpluses with us? We had already made changes where we could to make the text look more balanced. We needed specific and enforceable commitments by China to make structural changes to ensure that the agreement had support and sustainability. That was the only way the president would ever agree or that I could convince people in the United States that this agreement was different than the agreements China had failed to fulfill in the past.

The language we were discussing had been agreed upon for weeks or months. We were devolving rather than evolving. I huddled with Secretary Mnuchin and my deputy, Ambassador Jeffrey Gerrish, to confirm that they shared my views of the significance of China’s proposed changes and its movement backward. In a private session with the vice premier, Secretary Mnuchin and I asked that the Chinese side send us their revisions to one of the chapters of the agreement, which we believed would be the intellectual property chapter, to show us an example of the changes they sought. We left Beijing disappointed.

When we received the revised text of the intellectual property chapter later that week, it confirmed our worst fears. The document was a sea of redlines. China struck out major portions of agreed-upon text covering important specific commitments, unquestionably reneging on its commitments. Over the weekend, Secretary Mnuchin and I briefed the president on China’s actions. The president issued a tweet on May 5 indicating that the tariffs on the $200 billion of List 3 Chinese goods would increase from 10% to 25% and that the remaining Chinese imports not already covered by tariffs could face 25% tariffs. Showing the unity across diverse viewpoints within the administration, Secretary Mnuchin and I briefed the press the following day together with Larry Kudlow and Peter Navarro. 

Tensions escalated quickly. On May 10, we increased the tariffs from 10 percent to 25 percent on the $200 billion of List 3 Chinese imports and began the process for raising tariffs on essentially all remaining imports from China, which were valued at approximately $300 billion (“List 4”). China announced that it would increase tariff rates on the $60 billion of U.S. goods that it had not yet hit. Days later, the U.S. Department of Commerce placed Chinese tech giant Huawei and 68 of its affiliates on its Entity List, effectively cutting those companies off from exports of sensitive U.S. technology. Not to be outdone, China reported that it was working to establish an “Unreliable Entities List” of banned U.S. companies.

We were now two years into this effort to rebalance our relationship with China, and it was apparent that China’s leadership had no intentions of changing.

We were now two years into this effort to rebalance our relationship with China, and it was apparent that China’s leadership had no intentions of changing. At least the tariffs were in place. They would have the effect of counteracting China’s unfair trading practices, putting economic pressure on the Chinese government to make a deal, and in the meantime discouraging U.S. corporate investment in and supply chain integration with China.

We had confirmed that while individual Chinese officials may act in good faith, the hard-liners held more power back home. Painstaking work through details may be the way to get initial commitments, but would they be worth anything? What we’d need to find was a way to make those commitments enforceable. As the tariffs went into effect, it was time to have another serious meeting, one where the president would step in personally.

End Game

In June 2019, it was announced that President Trump would meet President Xi at the end of the month on the sidelines of yet another G20 meeting, this one in Osaka, Japan. Once again, I made the trip with President Trump and attended the meeting with President Xi on June 29. Considering all that had happened, I thought the meeting was friendly and productive. While the current tariffs remained in place, the two sides agreed not to escalate further and to resume negotiations. In addition, President Xi agreed that China would immediately begin making significant new purchases of U.S. agricultural products.

Wasting no time after the meeting in Osaka, we had conference calls with Vice Premier Liu on July 9 and July 18. Joining him for the first time on these calls was the Chinese minister of commerce, Zhong Shan. Minister Zhong was viewed as a hardliner whose participation in the discussions could impede progress. The vice premier raised two issues unrelated to our trade talks. One was arms sales that the United States had made to Taiwan. The other was the treatment of Huawei by the United States. The Chinese regularly raised issues unconnected to our trade negotiations that their officials viewed as affecting the “atmosphere” for the talks.

In contrast, an issue that clearly was related to our trade talks and that was essential to keeping them on track was President Xi’s agreement at Osaka to make immediate and significant purchases of U.S. agricultural products. When I raised that commitment, the vice premier surprisingly indicated that President Xi had only agreed that the two sides could have talks on possible agricultural purchases. He also offered several reasons why additional agricultural purchases may not be possible, including the continuation of the tariffs on Chinese goods. To avoid any possible confusion, I stressed in the strongest possible terms the urgency of the situation and that we understood President Xi to have agreed to proceed immediately with increased agricultural purchases. In our call on July 18, the vice premier stated that China would make agricultural purchases starting the next day.

Structural issues were more important than purchases in the long run, but the purchases were a vital test of good faith and enforcement, and the Chinese were failing it.

We agreed to conduct our next face-to-face meetings in Shanghai on July 30 and 31, but by then had a serious problem. China was not following through on making immediate and substantial agricultural purchases, repeating a pattern of unfulfilled commitments to such purchases throughout the negotiations. Structural issues were more important than purchases in the long run, but the purchases were a vital test of good faith and enforcement, and the Chinese were failing it. Despite our efforts to convey the urgency of the situation to the vice premier, we received a lukewarm response.

After we briefed the president upon our return from Shanghai, he directed me to move forward with imposing 10% tariffs on the remaining Chinese imports not already subject to tariffs starting on September 1. These were the so-called List 4 tariffs and would be in addition to the 25% tariffs then in place on $250 billion worth of Chinese imports from the first three lists. We soon received requests from U.S. companies to delay at least part of the tariffs because of the impact they would have on those companies and American consumers during the holiday season. List 4 included more consumer goods, such as clothing, footwear, laptop computers, and video game consoles. Considering our goal throughout this process of minimizing the pain on U.S. parties, we decided to delay the tariffs on $160 billion of the $280 billion in remaining Chinese imports until December 15. Thus, new tariffs would go into effect on September 1 for $120 billion in Chinese imports (“List 4A”) and on December 15 for the other $160 billion in Chinese imports (“List 4B”).

China announced its retaliation in the form of additional tariffs on $75 billion of U.S. goods on August 23. Once more, China had miscalculated. They had never been up against a president as tough as President Trump. He followed the negotiations, he knew the issues, and he was determined to correct the relationship. China still had not addressed the unfair trade practices identified in the Section 301 report and instead chose yet again to retaliate against the United States to protect and defend those practices. In the process, it tried to inflict more harm on the U.S. economy. As a result, the president directed me to again increase the tariffs—this time on the Chinese goods in Lists 4A and 4B from 10% to 15% and on the $250 billion of Lists 1, 2, and 3 Chinese goods from 25% to 30%, starting on October 1. On September 1, the 15% tariffs on the $120 billion of List 4A Chinese goods went into effect.

On a September 4 call with Vice Premier Liu and his team, I proposed meetings at the deputy level during the week of September 16, exchanges of text before and after those meetings, and a principal-level meeting in early October. In those September discussions, it became increasingly clear that certain subject areas might have greater prospects for agreement than others, including forced technology transfer, intellectual property, financial services barriers and market access, agricultural barriers and market access, and purchases.

As we entered October 2019, it appeared that we were building momentum. However, we had been in this situation before, only to see things break down. On October 10, the first day of the principal-level meetings, we started with a discussion of enforcement. We revisited the fundamental issue of who decides whether there has been a violation of the agreement and what action may be taken in response to that violation. Once again, I asserted our position that it should be the aggrieved or complaining party who decides those issues. We did not want to have panels of arbitrators from other countries make the decisions. We made significant headway on the intellectual property, forced technology transfer, agricultural barriers, market access, currency and enforcement chapters. China continued to raise its own issues, some of which were new and some of which related to areas outside of our trade discussions. The vice premier also continued to insist on the removal of all tariffs as a bottom-line position. We did not engage on these issues.

Because we would keep the tariffs in place throughout the talks on the later parts, the United States maintained its leverage.

Although President Trump and I previously had not wanted to do a phased agreement, it had become apparent that a comprehensive agreement covering the breadth and depth of all the issues we had been discussing with China would not be possible in the near term. We briefed the president and decided to do the agreement in phases, with the first phase covering the areas on which we had made substantial progress in our meetings and a second and possibly third phase to cover the other areas. Because we would keep the tariffs in place throughout the talks on the later parts, the United States maintained its leverage.

On October 11, the president met with the vice premier in the Oval Office and announced that we had reached an agreement in principle on a Phase One trade deal that would require China to make important structural changes in the areas of intellectual property, forced technology transfer, agriculture, services, and currency. The deal also would require China to significantly increase its purchases of U.S. manufactured goods, agricultural goods, energy, and services. We announced a final agreement on December 13.

Chess and Checkers

Most observers thought that the announcement of the agreement meant we were done. However, an entirely new negotiation was about to start—the negotiation over the translation of the English text into the Chinese text. At times, this negotiation would prove nearly as intense and challenging as the negotiation over the original text, and it lasted until the early morning hours of the day the agreement was to be signed.

Although there were extensive battles over the translations of various terms, the most difficult fight was over whether the term “ying” or “jiang” should be used as the Chinese translation for “shall.” Our Chinese-language experts at USTR insisted that “ying” was the appropriate Chinese term to use for “shall” because it represented an obligation, whereas “jiang” represented the future tense relating to something a party merely planned to do in the future. However, the Chinese side vehemently disagreed, arguing that the use of “ying” was inappropriate and even insulting.

We consulted outside Chinese-language experts, including one who had worked on important agreements with China over several decades while serving with the U.S. embassy in Beijing. They all confirmed that if we wanted the term to convey an obligation, we should continue to insist on using “ying.” After several conference calls between Ambassador Gerrish and Vice Minister Liao on this issue, the Chinese finally relented and agreed to use “ying.” 

As we went through this “ying versus jiang” discussion internally at USTR, I asked my staff to bring me the famous cyber-intrusion agreement that President Obama had made with President Xi. I wanted to see which Chinese word that agreement had used. After some delay and checking around the government, my staff discovered that neither word had been used in Obama’s agreement. That was because the agreement had never been written down. There had not even been a joint press release agreed to. This vaunted “agreement” was nothing but a U.S. press release.

I realized again why the Chinese side was so surprised by our approach. They were used to dealing with Americans who were more interested in a show than actual enforceable agreements.

I realized again why the Chinese side was so surprised by our approach. They were used to dealing with Americans who were more interested in a show than actual enforceable agreements.

On January 15, 2020, President Trump and Vice Premier Liu signed the Phase One Agreement. Many critics quickly jumped to the conclusion without reading the agreement that it was merely a purchases deal that did not address significant issues. They could not have been more wrong.

The deal most importantly kept the tariffs in place. This fundamentally changed our economic relationship. Further, China agreed to make significant and systemic changes to protect intellectual property, to stop forced technology transfers, and to facilitate U.S. market access in agriculture and financial services. It undertook obligations not to manipulate its currency. And uniquely, this agreement was fully enforceable.

These negotiations were historic. This was the first time that a U.S. president had directly challenged China, or directly challenged the free-trade consensus to protect our workers. No sensible person thought the Phase One deal would be the final stroke in rebalancing trade with China, the coup de grace in our all-important competition with this adversary. Rather, it was a monumental course correction toward mitigating an existential threat—to quote Winston Churchill in 1942, “the end of the beginning” of strategic decoupling, if fully enforced. What is needed now are restrictions on investment in both directions, a concerted effort to disentangle technology, and more tariffs to assure balanced trade.

Robert Lighthizer
Amb. Robert Lighthizer is the former U.S. Trade Representative in the Trump administration and deputy trade representative in the Reagan administration.
Recommended Reading
The Case for a Hard Break With China

In Foreign Affairs, Oren Cass and Gabriela Rodriguez make the case for why economic de-risking is ot Enough

Policy Brief: End “Permanent Normal Trade Relations” with China

Reclaiming control of U.S. trade policy

Bad Trade

“Bad competitiveness” results in weakening demand, which either reduces global production or requires surging debt to maintain demand and production at its existing level. Perhaps that rings a bell, because it is the world we live in.

Policy Brief: End “Permanent Normal Trade Relations” with China

May 17, 2023 - Globalization

Reclaiming control of U.S. trade policy

Download Policy Brief (PDF)
RECOMMENDED READING
The Case for a Hard Break With China
Only Trump Could Confront China
Bad Trade

What’s the Problem?

  • China disregards the rules of international trade, restricting access to its own market, distorting foreign markets with subsidies, and stealing intellectual property.
  • The resulting trade imbalances, declining domestic investment, and reduction in production capacity continually harm American industry and workers.
  • Expecting China would play by the rules, the U.S. welcomed it to the WTO, extending the privileges of permanent normal trade relations—and making it harder for U.S. policymakers to protect American interests.

Mortgaging Our Future

World Trade Organization (WTO) members like the United States are expected to extend permanent normal trade relations (PNTR) to each other. Countries like China that routinely violate WTO rules still benefit from these protections, with little consequence. China obstructs access to its market, steals intellectual property, and coerces foreign firms. Attempts to defend American interests have backfired, with the WTO ruling against the U.S. for defending its own interests.

Granting PNTR to China as part of its ascension to the WTO was supposed to grant American firms and workers comparable benefits in the Chinese market. But the experts were wrong.

China’s ascension to the WTO triggered a rapid increase in offshoring and import competition. This “China Shock” cost millions of American jobs, reduced domestic investment and innovative capacity, strained many communities’ social fabric, and contributed to a surge in “deaths of despair” concentrated among middle-aged Americans without college degrees.

What’s the Solution?

Congress should revoke China’s PNTR status and refuse to treat China as a free trade partner.

Moving forward, Congress should debate the status of Chinese trade relations annually, issuing regular policy determinations about how to regulate trade with China, as it did before it relinquished its authority to the WTO.

A Real Reset

Despite its handicaps, the WTO still provides a useful legal framework for trade amongst law-abiding countries.

The U.S. should continue to enjoy the benefits of WTO membership where possible while refusing to abide by one-sided WTO constraints that trading partners disregard. By rescinding PNTR status, the United States would signal to China that it will no longer tolerate open violation of trade norms. The global community would understand that American trade policy will be dictated by American interests, not weak international bodies.

Without PNTR status, all products from China would by default be subject to the higher tariff. This would reduce offshoring by discouraging American investors and corporations from doing business in China. The diminishing demand for Chinese goods would bolster American producers.

Frequently Raised Objections

“The United States should not abandon the established global economic order.”

The WTO’s legal framework provides a useful default for American companies productively engaged in the global economy. Outright WTO withdrawal could do more harm than good and is not tailored to address the China challenge. The U.S. should not hesitate to reject WTO rules and standards when they are not in the national interest. Congress voted to suspend Russia’s PNTR status after the invasion of Ukraine—with strong support from many of those most concerned about maintaining the international order. The much graver long-term threat of our current trade dynamic with China merits at least as strong a response.

“Rescinding China’s PNTR will start a harmful trade war.”

America is already in a harmful trade war. At no time have the WTO’s paper-thin constraints altered China’s decisions about how to act in its interest. Any hope of ending that war on acceptable terms requires a credible commitment by the United States to defend its own interests and retaliate against Chinese abuses.

“Increasing tariffs on goods from China will raise prices for Americans.”

Even very large tariffs have barely detectable short-term effects on consumer prices, and every dollar of tariffs can go toward reducing other taxes or costs that families face. In practice, much of a tariff’s cost will be borne by foreign producers who must cut prices to compete in our market, which economists found to be the case when President Trump imposed tariffs on specific goods from China. In the long run, as firms invest in domestic capacity and innovation, consumers may even benefit from lower prices as a result.

Further Reading

Recommended Reading
The Case for a Hard Break With China

In Foreign Affairs, Oren Cass and Gabriela Rodriguez make the case for why economic de-risking is ot Enough

Only Trump Could Confront China

The inside story of the trade negotiation that changed the world

Bad Trade

“Bad competitiveness” results in weakening demand, which either reduces global production or requires surging debt to maintain demand and production at its existing level. Perhaps that rings a bell, because it is the world we live in.

Bad Trade

Michael Pettis October 7, 2022 - Globalization

When nations compete by suppressing wages, globalization can leave us all poorer

RECOMMENDED READING
The Case for a Hard Break With China
Only Trump Could Confront China
Policy Brief: End “Permanent Normal Trade Relations” with China

“China will compete for some low-wage jobs with Americans,” lectured Nobel laureate Robert Solow from the White House podium, amidst the U.S. debate over China’s ascension to the World Trade Organization. “And their market will provide jobs for higher wage, more skilled people. And that’s a bargain for us.” More than 20 years later, economists and policymakers are still searching for that bargain. Belatedly, they are discovering that whether or not trade benefits the global economy or any particular nation depends, like most things in economics, on the specific underlying economic conditions.

When it comes to trade, the key conditions are the approaches that countries take in their quests for international competitiveness. Trade can directly boost production and indirectly boost demand, so that the global economy is generally better off. But trade can also make the global economy worse off by directly constraining demand and so indirectly constraining production. The outcome depends on whether a country’s higher export revenues are recycled into higher consumption and imports or into higher savings.

In the traditional view, international trade allows a country or region to specialize in producing things that it can produce relatively more efficiently than its trading partners, and so trade shifts production to the locale in which a given amount of labor and capital yields the greatest output. In a world of scarce inputs, this allows the global economy to maximize production. According to that model, by definition, anything that impedes or distorts free trade, whether a regulation or tariff or quota, reduces global production. Mainstream economists accept that the benefits of free trade may be badly distributed, even to the point at which free trade can leave some sectors worse off, but this, they insist, is a distribution problem that should be solved politically. The world, they argue, is always collectively worse off when any country intervenes in the free flow of goods.

This goes for each individual country’s policy choices too. “The economist’s case for free trade is essentially a unilateral case,” Nobel laureate Paul Krugman wrote in 1997. “A country serves its own interests by pursuing free trade regardless of what other countries may do.”

“What happens if, instead, the country achieves competitiveness by suppressing wage growth relative to increases in productivity, which means paying workers a lower share of what they produce than its trade partners pay their workers? This creates a form of “bad competitiveness,” which results in weakening demand for goods and services.”

Lurking behind these convictions is a series of assumptions that are simply not true, at least not in the regime that currently governs global trade and capital flows. In a well-functioning trading system, a country should become internationally more competitive by exploiting natural and geographical advantages and investing in research, manufacturing facilities and infrastructure to increase the productivity of workers. This “good competitiveness” results in rising production, and as the benefits of rising production are distributed to workers in the form of rising wages and benefits, workers are then able to increase their demand for other goods and services.

But that is not the only option. What happens if, instead, the country achieves competitiveness by suppressing wage growth relative to increases in productivity, which means paying workers a lower share of what they produce than its trade partners pay their workers? This creates a form of “bad competitiveness,” which results in weakening demand for goods and services, which in turn either reduces global production, or requires surging debt to maintain demand and production at its existing level. Perhaps that rings a bell, because it is the world we live in.

How to Become “Competitive”

In our hyperglobalized world, in which transportation, communication and financial transaction costs have dropped to almost zero, production shifts easily to countries in which wages are relatively low. What matters—and this is a point often missed in the debate about trade—is not the absolute level of wages. What drives competitiveness is the total compensation households receive in the form of wages, salaries, investment income and transfers relative to their productivity levels.

A simple example illustrates the point: Suppose workers in the United States earn $20 per hour in a t-shirt factory while in China they earn $1 per hour. Where should the production locate? The casual observer might say it will move to China, which has “cheap labor.” But if American t-shirt workers are earning 20 times more than their Chinese counterparts because (as economists would assume) they are 20 times as productive, then the Chinese labor is not actually cheaper at all. There is no competitive advantage in paying $1 per hour instead of $20 if it takes 20 hours to get the same output.

When we say colloquially that production shifts to China in that scenario because of cheap labor, what we mean is that the labor costs one twentieth as much and is perhaps a tenth as productive. In America, you have to pay $20 to get $20 of output. In China, you can pay $1 and get $2 of output. The “competitiveness” of China’s “cheap labor” is in fact just the opportunity for the producer to capture more of the value for itself.

That is why “competitive” wages can be an advantage in both high-wage countries, like Germany, Japan, the Netherlands, and South Korea, and in lower-wage countries, like China and Vietnam. Their workers and middle classes receive less relative to their levels of productivity than do the workers of their trading partners. At the macroeconomic level, this means that the ratio of household income to GDP is lower than among their trading partners.

There are many ways to reduce household income relative to GDP, all of which depend on policies that explicitly or implicitly transfer income from households to businesses. Most obviously, a nation can keep wages “competitive” by suppressing wage growth directly, as happened in Germany with the “Hartz” labor reforms of 2003–05. These reforms cut worker protections and reduced unemployment benefits, setting off a several-year period during which wage growth slowed significantly relative to the growth in worker productivity, effectively transferring income from workers to businesses.

“It is strange, then, that economists complain about the distorting effect of tariffs and other direct trade interventions while ignoring all the other indirect mechanisms that do exactly the same thing.”

There are other ways. Policymakers can achieve the same effect by reducing pensions, suppressing the returns households receive on their savings, or undermining the social safety net. In the 2000s, for example, China repressed interest rates on household savings, imposed residency restrictions that severely weakened the bargaining power of migrant workers, and gradually dismantled the so-called “iron rice bowl” of lifetime job security, forcing down the share of GDP retained by Chinese households from roughly 65% in the mid-1980s to just over 50% by 2010. As that happened, Chinese workers consumed a declining share of what they produced and China’s export “competitiveness” automatically increased.

Policies that weaken labor movements and other sources of worker power are also economic tools for shifting national income from labor to capital. Less intuitively, tolerance for environmental degradation reduces operating costs for businesses and increases health costs for households, creating an implicit transfer from households to businesses that makes the latter more “competitive” in the global marketplace.

Depreciating the currency is yet another way of increasing international competitiveness by forcing households to subsidize businesses, although the mechanism is often misunderstood. A cheaper currency is basically a transfer from net importers, who must pay more for the products they consume, to net exporters, who benefit from higher foreign prices. Because all households are effectively net importers, and because most net exporters are manufacturers, farmers, and commodity producers, depreciating the currency is just another way of transferring income from households to subsidize producers. The same can work with interest rates. In economies like Japan’s in the 1980s and China’s in the 2000s, artificially repressing interest rates caused a direct transfer of income from households, who were net savers, to manufacturers, state-owned enterprises, and local governments, who were net borrowers. Needless to say, this borrowing subsidy, paid for by Japanese or Chinese household savers, raised the international “competitiveness” of their manufacturers.

Even tariffs should be viewed through this lens. When a country imposes tariffs on a foreign import, it boosts the profits of domestic manufacturers at the expense of domestic consumers of the product. In aggregate, tariffs work like all the other mechanisms, by transferring income from household consumers to the manufacturing sector. It is strange, then, that economists complain about the distorting effect of tariffs and other direct trade interventions while ignoring all the other indirect mechanisms that do exactly the same thing. Policies that put downward pressure on the currency, reduce interest rates on household savings, undermine the social safety net, encourage environmental degradation, weaken labor unions, and so on, leverage the same dynamic as tariffs: they increase a country’s international competitiveness and suppress domestic demand by forcing households to subsidize production.

Subsidies, Savings, and Surpluses

One of the greatest sources of confusion in the discussion of trade is the role of cultural and household preferences in a country’s savings rate. Many analysts point approvingly to what they believe is a culture of thrift in high-savings countries like Germany, China, and Japan, while making invidious comparisons with the spendthrift ways of low-savings countries like the United States, Spain, and England.

But how much a country saves has little to do with culture and is mostly a function of the distribution of income between households and other sectors of economy. By definition, savings comprise everything that is produced but not consumed. Because different sectors within the economy have different consumption propensities, a country’s savings rate—or the obverse, which is its consumption rate—is determined largely by how these sectors share the national income. Workers and middle-class households, for example, typically consume most of what they earn, and save very little. Businesses consume none of what they earn or, put another way, save all of it. The rich consume very little of what they earn and save most of it. Most government revenues, rather than being spent directly on consumption, are either recycled to other sectors via transfer payments or else invested in development of public assets. This is especially the case in countries like China, where the government allocates a substantial share of national income to investment in infrastructure and state-owned or -subsidized enterprises.

What determines a country’s overall savings rate is the way in which income is distributed among these different groups. Policies that transfer income from workers or the middle class to the rich or to businesses, for example, automatically force up the national savings rate regardless of culture. That is why it is not a coincidence that high-savings countries like Germany, China, and Japan are also countries in which households retain a lower share of GDP than other countries at similar stages of development.

“Whether the global economy benefits from surplus countries exporting their excess savings depends crucially on where those excess savings go.”

Nor is it a coincidence that high-savings countries run persistent trade surpluses. Total domestic demand consists of household and government consumption plus business and government investment. Because businesses invest mostly to serve domestic demand, if domestic consumption is low, this often means that private business investment is also low. The consequence of households receiving a low share of what they produce is that domestic demand tends to be weaker than otherwise.

Normally, weaker demand should mean slower growth, but this is why trade surpluses matter so much to these economies. Exporting the excess production is what allows them to continue manufacturing, even when they cannot absorb what is produced domestically. Exporting excess production, in other words, is the same thing as exporting excess savings, and countries with trade surpluses are by definition exporting their excess savings to the rest of the world. Or, looked at another way, countries with trade surpluses are effectively exporting their domestic demand deficiencies to the rest of the world.

Whether the global economy benefits from surplus countries exporting their excess savings depends crucially on where those excess savings go. A rapidly growing developing economy may have very high domestic investment needs that are constrained by the scarcity of domestic savings. Exporting savings to such countries can allow them to invest more, in which case the deficient demand of the surplus country is matched by higher demand abroad as investment in developing countries rises. This leaves the world better off because both total global production and total global demand are higher, even with a demand deficiency in the surplus country. This was the story in the 19th century, when the United States was rapidly developing and British and other European capital inflows allowed it to invest far more than it could have done just with domestic savings.

The Problem of Unbalanced Trade

But—and here is what many economists miss—when a country exports excess savings it doesn’t necessarily lead to higher investment elsewhere. When excess savings are exported to advanced economies, like the United States today, domestic investment doesn’t rise. For the past several decades, American businesses have been reluctant to invest mainly because of weak expected demand for their products, not because they lacked access to cheap capital. On the contrary, capital has been cheap and plentiful, and businesses sit on large hoards of cash which they use mainly for share repurchases or acquisitions of existing business.

Under these conditions, foreign inflows of excess savings won’t cause U.S. investment to rise. But as a net recipient of foreign capital inflows, the U.S. must nonetheless run a current account (trade) deficit, which is another way of saying that its investment must exceed its savings. The conclusion seems surprising but is inescapable: if net capital inflows do not cause investment to rise, they must cause savings to fall.

For many Americans, and even many economists, this is totally counterintuitive. We are used to thinking that the U.S. controls every aspect of its economic fate, and that the very low American savings rate is wholly a function of faulty American attitudes towards thrift.

But this simply isn’t true. A country, like the United States, with open capital markets, high-quality governance, and a flexible financial system, has little to no control over the extent of net capital inflows, which occurs as savers abroad purchase assets from Americans. Foreign central banks looking to manage their currencies, wealthy oligarchs protecting their wealth, Asian fund managers scrambling for investment opportunities, European speculators playing currency and interest games, along with an enormous variety of other investors who collectively export 30–50% of the world’s excess savings into the U.S. are determined to convert that savings into American assets. So long as they are willing to keep bidding higher, they will find willing sellers, and the capital will flow stateside.

If the U.S. cannot control the extent of net capital inflows, then by definition it cannot control the gap between domestic investment and domestic savings. In the 19th century it was mostly American domestic investment that fluctuated in response to changes in net foreign capital inflows. Today, when investment is constrained by weak demand, it is mostly American savings that must fluctuate in response to changes in net foreign capital inflows.

“As long as countries can improve their international competitiveness by directly or indirectly suppressing wages and reducing domestic demand, and as long as they can externalize the resulting cost by exporting savings abroad, the incentive for countries to increase their international competitiveness ends up depressing global wages and global demand.”

Net capital inflows, in other words, force down American savings, and this can occur through several channels. If foreign capital inflows cause the U.S. dollar to strengthen, for example, the stronger dollar effectively transfers income from manufacturers (net exporters) to households (net importers), and so raises the consumption share of GDP. If a stronger dollar causes foreign manufacturers to price American manufacturers out of business, and these American manufacturers respond by laying off workers, this also lowers the American savings rate (unemployed workers have a negative savings rate).

What if the Federal Reserve tries to counter this rise in unemployment by lowering interest rates? In that case, lower interest rates encourage households to borrow more and so maintain consumption levels. Similarly, Washington may try to counter the rise in unemployment by expanding the fiscal deficit. Because debt is negative savings, in either case the American savings rate must decline.

Still another channel is if foreign purchases of American stocks, bonds, and real estate cause their prices to rise, triggering a wealth effect in which American asset-holders feel more secure with their existing savings. This will encourage them to increase their consumption and reduce the amount of their income they save.

The point is that as long as countries can improve their international competitiveness by directly or indirectly suppressing wages and reducing domestic demand, and as long as they can externalize the resulting cost by exporting savings abroad, the incentive for countries to increase their international competitiveness ends up depressing global wages and global demand. This is especially a problem for countries like the U.S., whose deep, flexible, open and well-governed capital markets mean that they must automatically absorb these excess savings, in which case the American savings must decline to accommodate the flood of foreign savings. This decline must occur either in the form of higher unemployment, higher household debt, or higher fiscal deficits.

The problem is not free trade per se. The problem is a system in which trade depresses wages rather than raises productivity. The United States should take the lead in reforming this very unbalanced global trade regime, not by turning against trade but rather by eliminating the conditions that allow grossly unbalanced trade. Either Washington should pioneer new trade agreements that directly restrict the ability of countries to run large and persistent surpluses, much as John Maynard Keynes proposed during the Bretton Woods conference, or it should unilaterally refuse to continue playing its role of absorber of last resort of global excess savings and instead force its own trade and capital flows into balance.

When trade between countries directly boosts production and indirectly boosts demand, the global economy is better off. When it directly constrains demand and so indirectly constrains production, not only is the global economy worse off, but countries like the United States bear an especially heavy cost to keep the system afloat. The purpose of international trade should be to maximize overall productivity and, with it, to increase welfare. It should not allow individual countries to maximize domestic production at the expense of their trading partners.

Michael Pettis
Michael Pettis is a senior fellow at the Carnegie Endowment and a finance professor at Peking University. His most recent book is Trade Wars Are Class Wars (2021).
@michaelxpettis
Recommended Reading
The Case for a Hard Break With China

In Foreign Affairs, Oren Cass and Gabriela Rodriguez make the case for why economic de-risking is ot Enough

Only Trump Could Confront China

The inside story of the trade negotiation that changed the world

Policy Brief: End “Permanent Normal Trade Relations” with China

Reclaiming control of U.S. trade policy

CHIPS Won’t Help China

Oren Cass July 27, 2022 - Globalization
RECOMMENDED READING
The Case for a Hard Break With China
Only Trump Could Confront China
Policy Brief: End “Permanent Normal Trade Relations” with China

Opponents of the CHIPS Act, which provides more than $70 billion in funding for domestic semiconductor manufacturing, have spent the past two weeks cycling through weak critiques that persuaded no one—Republican support in the Senate increased between the initial procedural vote and final passage. Perhaps unsurprisingly then, as the bill moves on to the House, opponents are doubling down on their most incendiary argument, even if it’s one that bears no relationship to reality: CHIPS, they say, won’t help the U.S. outcompete China. It actually helps China.

A good illustration comes from Heritage president Kevin Roberts, who went on Fox Business to warn that the bill “subsidizes the construction of semiconductor factories in China.” He suggested legislators think about “going back home to my district next month having voted for something that uses my voters’ taxpayers money to go to the construction of factories in China.” One imagines the grassroots mailers may already be rolling off the presses.

This is the sort of untruth that should probably just be called a lie, if not for the possibility that critics may be genuinely confused. So, to be clear: CHIPS creates no incentives to build factories in China, and creates no authority to send taxpayer dollars toward such construction. Funding is clearly limited to projects in the United States. This may help explain why the leading architects of the Trump Administration’s China policy—Secretary of State Mike Pompeo, National Security Advisor Robert O’Brien, and U.S. Trade Representative Robert Lighthizer—all support the bill.

Continue Reading at The American Conservative
Oren Cass
Oren Cass is the executive director at American Compass.
@oren_cass
Recommended Reading
The Case for a Hard Break With China

In Foreign Affairs, Oren Cass and Gabriela Rodriguez make the case for why economic de-risking is ot Enough

Only Trump Could Confront China

The inside story of the trade negotiation that changed the world

Policy Brief: End “Permanent Normal Trade Relations” with China

Reclaiming control of U.S. trade policy

Cutting China Tariffs Will Offer No Respite From Rising Prices

Oren Cass May 1, 2022 - Globalization
RECOMMENDED READING
The Case for a Hard Break With China
Only Trump Could Confront China
Policy Brief: End “Permanent Normal Trade Relations” with China

A campaign is under way, led by officials in the Biden administration, to convince Americans that slashing tariffs on Chinese imports might offer relief from rapidly rising prices. That is not remotely the case — indeed, the argument is hard to deliver without a wry grin and a chuckle. But watch which economists embrace it, happy to use any pretext for advancing their underlying free-trade agenda. And watch which politicians, until now eager to win votes by talking tough on China, leap casually off that train and on to an inflation express running in the opposite direction.

The economic problem with pitching a tariff rollback as inflation response is two-fold. First, a tariff of any given size might affect the price level but it does nothing to the rate of change. A tariff imposed in 2018 could perhaps have caused a price increase in 2018, but it cannot bear responsibility for prices rising in 2022.

Likewise, a tariff eliminated in the second quarter of 2022 might cause a onetime downward shift in prices — say, an 8.8 per cent inflation print in the third quarter instead of 9 per cent — but it will not affect whatever combination of forces is driving inflation to begin with. If inflation the following quarter would have been headed towards 9 per cent with tariffs in place, it will still be heading towards 9 per cent with the tariffs gone.

Thus, a tariff reduction is not so much an inflation-fighting tool as an arbitrary subsidy offered on a particular category of goods. Policymakers could just as easily take the tariff revenue and pay it to the sellers of pitted fruits and haircuts, reducing the price of those goods.

Continue Reading at Financial Times
Oren Cass
Oren Cass is the executive director at American Compass.
@oren_cass
Recommended Reading
The Case for a Hard Break With China

In Foreign Affairs, Oren Cass and Gabriela Rodriguez make the case for why economic de-risking is ot Enough

Only Trump Could Confront China

The inside story of the trade negotiation that changed the world

Policy Brief: End “Permanent Normal Trade Relations” with China

Reclaiming control of U.S. trade policy

Trading It All Away

Marco Rubio December 10, 2021 - Globalization

China and the WTO at 20: How the bipartisan economic consensus is destroying American greatness

RECOMMENDED READING
The Case for a Hard Break With China
Only Trump Could Confront China
Policy Brief: End “Permanent Normal Trade Relations” with China

Henry Clay is especially appropriate for a lecture series focused on the long-term interests of our country. During his time in public life, he was known for taking the long view on the best interests of a then-infant republic. He had a very specific vision for American economic policy. To summarize: First, he didn’t want American prosperity to depend on any other country; and second, he wanted ours to be a diverse industrial economy.

That vision, and the work of those who followed him, steered the course of history. Economic independence helped to preserve the union in the early years of our republic. And, less than 100 years later, industrial capacity and diversity became the war machine that tipped the scales of World War II. Now we stand here a century and a half later, and America once again finds itself at a historic pivot point—not just for America, but for the world.

The post-Cold War world is fading from view, and we are being rapidly pulled towards a new era in human history. But in this era, our nation is not being steered by statesmen like Henry Clay. In January, I tweeted, “Biden’s cabinet picks went to Ivy League schools, have strong resumes, attend all the right conferences. And they will be polite & orderly caretakers of America’s decline.” The condemnation was swift and loud.

The permanent bureaucracy that runs our government, the people who run our largest corporations, many of the think tanks that generate our ideas, and the media that cover our politics are all devout worshippers of a late 20th century ideology. This ideology was formed in the elite universities that inculcated in them the economic and political theology of a time much different from the one we are now entering. They are the authors, practitioners, and defenders of a post-Cold War bipartisan consensus that has dominated policymaking for the last three decades. We must either abandon this consensus or be forever defined as the generation that managed the steady decline of a once great nation.

The course of history is generally determined not by individual and dramatic decisions, but by the cumulative effect of incremental choices that people, nations, and governments make over time. But there are some singular moments whose impact are felt for generations. One of those moments occurred this week 20 years ago.

At least half of the items in any room across America are probably labeled “Made in China.” Why? It stems from that decision 20 years ago to allow Communist China to join the World Trade Organization (WTO)—a decision that now shapes how our most powerful corporations behave, what is available for us to buy here in America, and ultimately, the future of our country.

“Instead of exporting “economic freedom,” we exported our industrial strength, and the result has been an economic, social, and geopolitical disaster.”

Five years after China became a full member of the WTO, our trade deficit with them had nearly tripled. Before China’s ascension, the U.S. was the largest trading partner of 152 countries in the world. Today, we are the largest trading partner for only 57, while China is the largest trading partner of 128. This decision was a pivotal moment in world history—and 20 years later, it is increasingly acknowledged to be a critical mistake.

Why was it a mistake? Because it was rooted in the flawed assumption that global economic integration was more important than anything else: more important than dignified work for Americans, our ability to make things, and even our national security. This assumption was perfectly summarized by President Clinton when he said, â€śBy joining the WTO, China is not simply agreeing to import more of our products, it is agreeing to import one of democracy’s most cherished values—economic freedom.”

The fact that I do not need to spend any time convincing anyone that this is not how things turned out is a testament to how wrong they were. The damage that decision has inflicted on our families, communities, and country is almost incalculable. Instead of exporting “economic freedom,” we exported our industrial strength, and the result has been an economic, social, and geopolitical disaster.

Tens of thousands of American factories disappeared, and an estimated 2.5 million American manufacturing jobs were lost. This loss has contributed to historic declines in men’s labor force participation, wages, and even marriage. We’ve seen an opioid addiction crisis whose geographic hotspots happen to be the very regions most impacted by the loss of factories and jobs. This loss has led many Americans to believe that the American Dream is no longer in reach. This is the dream my immigrant parents and millions like them achieved here in this country: not a dream of becoming rich, but a dream to have a stable and dignified job that allows you to get married, start a family, own a home in a safe neighborhood, retire with dignity, and leave your children better off than yourself.

And this terrible mistake didn’t only hurt America; it empowered the Chinese Communist Party. They now use their new and growing economic strength and influence to turn American companies into their lobbyists, their spokespersons, and their advocates in Washington. They use it to tell our companies what to do with their businesses, coerce Hollywood studios and American sports leagues to self-censor, and intimidate international organizations to serve China’s interests at the world’s expense.

In Washington there is a greater and growing awareness of this reality. Many are actually very serious about doing something about it, while others just play along because they know it polls well.

But let there be no doubt: there are still very influential and powerful voices who cling to the failed consensus that brought us to this point, hoping the growing awareness of this danger we face is just a short-term movement, a populist fad that will soon fade. For the sake of our country and the world, I hope we prove them wrong. Because if they are proven right, and the attention to this problem is transitory, it will mean that most of us who are alive today will live to see the day when a genocidal communist regime ascends to become the most influential and powerful country in the world, while the greatest beacon of liberty in human history is relegated to a status of a once-great power in decline.

I think it is impossible to forge a different path forward without first understanding how the failed consensus that produced this current predicament developed. If we address the assumptions that led to this mistake, hopefully we’ll abandon them and, in the process, adopt the right assumptions.

“If … the attention to this problem is transitory, it will mean that most of us who are alive today will live to see the day when a genocidal communist regime ascends to become the most influential and powerful country in the world, while the greatest beacon of liberty in human history is relegated to a status of a once-great power in decline.”

The first flawed assumption was the belief that Americans are primarily consumers—that our primary economic identity isn’t as a worker, a parent, the head of household, or a member of a community, but as a shopper. If you believe that we derive our identity and happiness from the things we buy, and not from work, children, and family, then it becomes easy to justify opening up to China in exchange for cheaper prices. But we all know that what gives life meaning and purpose isn’t how many things we can buy or own—it’s the time we spend and things we do with our family and in our communities. That requires the stability that comes from good jobs.

To view Americans solely as consumers ignores the dignity that comes with work, and it ignores how corrosive it is to the individual and ultimately to a community when good jobs are no longer available. It leaves you with an unemployment rate, for example, that drops consistently below 5%, not because more people are working, but because more people have given up looking for dignified work and dropped out of the labor force.

It leaves you at the mercy of any disruption in the supply chains. When shortages make it harder to find what we want to buy and inflation makes everything more expensive, you still don’t have the jobs, the dignity, and the industrial capacity—and now you don’t even have the cheaper prices. That’s the predicament we unfortunately find ourselves in right now. Eventually, if cheaper prices at the store are the result of sending the job you once had to a cheaper worker in another country, you’re inevitably going to face widespread anger and despair.

And still, many don’t get it, ignore it, or hope we overlook it. When the Chamber of Commerce and the Business Roundtable petition the Biden Administration to lift Trump’s tariffs on China, or when 91 senators vote to cut tariffs on Chinese goods, it shows you just how deeply embedded this flawed thinking still is in our country.

The second assumption that underpinned the flawed bipartisan consensus was that the stock market and corporate profits are the same thing as real economic growth and innovation. For 20 years now, presidents from both parties have pointed to the stock market as a scoreboard indicating whether we are winning or losing economically. A thriving stock market is not a bad thing, nor is it unimportant. But our economy is a lot more than just the stock market. And most of the time, whether the market closes up or down has zero correlation with how the economy is working for our country, for our families, and for our communities.

Over the past two decades, the stock market has gone up 120% when adjusted for inflation, but “middle income” Americans have seen only seen marginal growth of about 6% over that same period. And lower income Americans have actually seen no growth at all.

“If you believe that we derive our identity and happiness from the things we buy, and not from work, children, and family, then it becomes easy to justify opening up to China in exchange for cheaper prices.”

The “Cost of Thriving Index” produced by Oren Cass found that in 1985, when my father was a banquet bartender in Coconut Grove, Florida, it took the median male worker 30 weeks of work to afford a year’s worth of the basics that it takes to raise a family. Today, that same index indicates it would take 53 weeks in a 52-week year to do the same thing.

When did this trend take off? It coincides almost perfectly with the collapse of American manufacturing after China entered the WTO. We lost 33% of our manufacturing jobs in just the first decade after that decision was made. It was a collapse so stunning that shortly after the year 2000, finance became a larger share of U.S. corporate profits than manufacturing.

Wall Street and Corporate America could now make the same products, or something new they invented, but at a lower cost, using cheaper workers working in a Chinese factory. The lower cost of manufacturing didn’t mean just cheaper consumer prices; it also meant larger corporate profits. Larger profits meant greater returns for shareholders, but it didn’t necessarily mean greater prosperity for working Americans.

There is nothing inherently wrong with greater profits for corporations and better returns for shareholders. But on their own, they are not a good way of measuring the strength of our economy and the well-being of our people. Lower prices alone can never make up for the fact that you lost the stability and dignity that comes from a well-paying job. Greater returns on investors’ stock portfolios can’t make up for the closure of a factory that left behind a hollowed-out community. And record corporate prices can’t make up for the insecurity that comes from being a nation that can’t make masks during a pandemic or produce the active ingredients in our most basic medicines.

Socialism is a failure. It’s a failure because it considers wealth to be immoral. It is possible to have a free market that generates wealth, while also benefiting working families and serving our national interest. But when you have an economy where wealth is being generated in a way that is divorced completely from the well-being of a people or the security of a country, it foments discontent and the resentment that Marxists always seek to exploit. It gives an opening to argue that capitalism is inherently unfair and repressive. And it creates an opportunity to argue that the time has come to abandon free enterprise and empower the government to “Build Back Better.”

When wealth is generated by sending our jobs and our manufacturing capacity to a country that seeks to rise at our expense, that views our relationship as a zero-sum game in which either it wins or we do, we are left vulnerable to whatever disruptions that country seeks to create and any coercion they seek to pursue.

“But our economy is a lot more than just the stock market. And most of the time, whether the market closes up or down has zero correlation with how the economy is working for our country, for our families, and for our communities.”

The third assumption behind the flawed bipartisan consensus was that if our companies sent our factories and jobs to China, it would give America more influence over China and the world. It is a misguided belief that is rooted in the once popular theory that the end of the Cold War signaled the “end of history.” The theory was best expressed by Francis Fukuyama, who argued that after the fall of the Soviet Union, the whole world would become democratic. The economic ties of globalization would reduce conflict, and mass communication would bridge cultural divides.

It may sound silly today, but not long ago there was a catchy talking point that was popular in college economics courses, conferences, and soundbites. To paraphrase, it something like this: “No two nations with a McDonald’s have ever gone to war with each other.” Twenty years ago, the world’s most powerful companies were American. So, the belief was that this new world centered on global commerce would inevitably lead, not just to more McDonald’s, but to greater American influence as well.

But that’s not how it turned out. We soon learned that you could eat Big Macs and still view the country that invented them as a rival to be defeated. And we learned that when American companies are forced to choose between what’s good for America and bigger profits, they will usually pick bigger profits.

The Chinese Communist Party never wasted any time believing that the “end of history” had arrived. They saw and still see history as thousands years of greatness interrupted by a century of shame and humiliation at the hands of the West. They viewed it as their destiny to become the world’s preeminent power at America’s expense. For a time, they chose to “hide their capacity” and “bide their time.” But by 2008, they felt strong enough to no longer pretend.

Our economy is now controlled by people who have more allegiance to the global economic order than to their own nation. Our leading companies have no problem helping China build missiles that may one day kill American soldiers or give China access to American semi-conductors if it means they can make bigger profits for the next quarterly reports. Our major corporations say the United States has “human rights” problems while proudly sponsoring Olympic Games hosted by a government responsible for genocide and slavery.

Our culture is now influenced by studios that produce movies about how evil our history is but proactively self-censor anything that would offend the China’s Communist Party because they want their movies distributed there. Our culture is also influenced by prominent athletes like LeBron James, who has no problem claiming our police departments are overrun by killer cops, and Colin Kaepernick, who has no problem making a documentary about how systemically racist and evil our country is. And yet, they both make millions of dollars endorsing shoes made by the slave labor of Uyghur Muslims in China.

“We soon learned that you could eat Big Macs and still view the country that invented them as a rival to be defeated. And we learned that when American companies are forced to choose between what’s good for America and bigger profits, they will usually pick bigger profits.”

In his first speech in the Senate, Henry Clay warned that some “have been engaged, to overthrow the American System, and to substitute the foreign.” He suggested that while they were “long a resident of this country,” they have “no feelings, no attachments, no sympathies, no principles, in common with our people.” His words spoke to a different time and place, and yet they have taken on new relevance and meaning in our day.

As noted earlier, the people running our country today are acting as caretakers of our decline. These are not foreign agents. They are not supporters per se of the genocide being committed by a communist regime. And yet, even as I speak to you now, some of the most powerful people in government and business are working to make sure my Uyghur Forced Labor Prevention Act never becomes law. Because they believe that making sure American consumers have access to iPhones and sneakers is so important that not even stopping slave labor should be allowed to stand in the way. They believe they must maximize the profits of their shareholders at any cost, even if it means relying on factories filled with slaves.

Perhaps the most dangerous result of the decision to open up to China is that it left us with people at the highest levels of government and business who consistently advocate for policies that serve the interests of a foreign power and damage the interests of our country. The defenders of this status quo often hide behind capitalism to defend their actions and stances. But an economic relationship in which one side must follow the rules and the other doesn’t is not capitalism.

Real capitalism—American capitalism—wouldn’t allow China to steal our trade secrets and then produce cheaper imitations to put our companies out of business. It wouldn’t let Chinese companies do whatever they want in America, while American companies are either banned in China or forced to partner with a Chinese company (who steal their trade secrets and then put them out of business). This isn’t about capitalism—this isn’t capitalism. This is about corporations and big investors who are making billions by cooperating with China and simply do not care that it is coming at the expense of their country and their fellow citizens.

“The defenders of this status quo often hide behind capitalism to defend their actions and stances. But an economic relationship in which one side must follow the rules and the other doesn’t is not capitalism.”

Lenin once predicted, “The capitalists will sell us the rope with which we will hang them.” For a least a decade now, everyday Americans have been telling us that the tradeoffs made two decades ago have not worked out well for them or our country. A fateful decision made on flawed assumptions accelerated the global rise of a communist regime at the expense of American workers, industrial capacity, and national security. And now, the commonsense wisdom of our people is finally beginning to find influence in our politics and government.

Forging a path towards a pro-American capitalism that protects our nation’s interests and serves the common good will not be easy. Some of the most powerful interests in our economy are deeply invested in the status quo, and many of the most powerful people in our government are too deeply committed to the road we are on now. But charting a new path is the only way forward. It will not be the work of one person or one party. To succeed, it must be the work of an entire generation and cross the entire political spectrum. It must become our new consensus. Only the free market can make this century a new American Century. But it must be a capitalism that serves the interests of our country, not the interests of the global economy. The market must serve our people, not the other way around.

What does that kind of future look like? It is a future where private industry, not government spending, creates good jobs for our people while also building the resiliency of our country. It is a future where taking risk can result in both wealth for those willing to take the risk of investment and innovation and prosperity for those willing to work and produce.

We live in a country and in a world that is much different than the one Henry Clay knew. And yet, ironically, a new American Century is in many ways not unlike the vision laid out by Henry Clay almost two hundred years ago: an America that does not depend on any other nation for its prosperity, and an America with the industrial capacity to tackle any challenges that comes our way.


Adapted from Senator Rubio’s remarks at the inaugural Henry Clay Lecture in Political Economy on December 8, 2021.

Marco Rubio
Marco Rubio is a U.S. senator from Florida.
@marcorubio
Recommended Reading
The Case for a Hard Break With China

In Foreign Affairs, Oren Cass and Gabriela Rodriguez make the case for why economic de-risking is ot Enough

Only Trump Could Confront China

The inside story of the trade negotiation that changed the world

Policy Brief: End “Permanent Normal Trade Relations” with China

Reclaiming control of U.S. trade policy

Marco Rubio Gets It. Our Economic Addiction to China Is a National Security Threat.

Henry Olsen December 8, 2021 - Globalization
RECOMMENDED READING
The Case for a Hard Break With China
Only Trump Could Confront China
Policy Brief: End “Permanent Normal Trade Relations” with China

Sen. Marco Rubio (R-Fla.) has spoken eloquently in recent years about the need to reorient the United States’ market economy to better support workers and families. His speech on Wednesday crystallizes that belief and persuasively shows how our lust for cheap goods is endangering our national security.

Rubio delivered his remarks at the inaugural Henry Clay Lecture at Hillsdale College’s D.C. campus for the conservative reform group American Compass. The group, headed by Oren Cass, has emerged in recent years as a leading entity — along with the think tank I am affiliated with, the Ethics and Public Policy Center — calling on conservatives to rethink their devotion to free market fundamentalism.

Continue Reading at The Washington Post
Henry Olsen
Henry Olsen is a senior fellow at the Ethics and Public Policy Center, an opinion columnist for the Washington Post, and author of The Working Class Republican: Ronald Reagan and the Return of Blue-Collar Conservatism (2017).
Recommended Reading
The Case for a Hard Break With China

In Foreign Affairs, Oren Cass and Gabriela Rodriguez make the case for why economic de-risking is ot Enough

Only Trump Could Confront China

The inside story of the trade negotiation that changed the world

Policy Brief: End “Permanent Normal Trade Relations” with China

Reclaiming control of U.S. trade policy

Why China Matters to You

Oren Cass November 19, 2021 - Globalization
RECOMMENDED READING
The Case for a Hard Break With China
Only Trump Could Confront China
Policy Brief: End “Permanent Normal Trade Relations” with China

In hindsight, it was the happiest of coincidences that global markets integrated during an era of American hegemony. In the moment, though, policymakers took for granted the presence of some indelible linkage: “Globalization” was synonymous with “liberalization.” Countries with McDonald’s didn’t fight each other. And trading freely with a communist, mercantilist dictatorship ruling over more than a billion impoverished peasants would help that nation transition to liberal democracy, enriching everyone along the way.

The naïveté makes occasional appearances still—for instance, last weekend’s New York Times essay by Ann-Marie Slaughter announces that “it’s time to ignore geopolitics” and insists that “great-power games, as deadly as they have been and could still be, must give way to planetary politics, in which human beings matter more than nationalities.” (The word “must” is striking here. One expects Xi Jinping might paraphrase Andrew Jackson on this point: the think-tank president has made her decision; now let her enforce it.)

Twenty years into the foolish experiment of Chinese ascension to the World Trade Organization, America now has a strategic peer whose values and goals in conflict with our own. We have committed to an international system on the assumption that we would set its course, and face a hoisting by our own petard if adversaries gain leverage within its institutions. One option might be to take our ball and go home, as we have already done in some forums. The United States wisely rejects the International Criminal Court and chuckles at the United Nations; Senator Josh Hawley has proposed withdrawing from the WTO. But as Elbridge Colby argues in this week’s Compass Point, After Hegemony, a world in which China is the dominant economic power will be one in which Americans find their lives increasingly controlled from Beijing.

This reality requires new thinking about American grand strategy and foreign policy. Debates in recent decades have focused almost entirely on intervention: who to bomb or invade, how long to stay, and to what end? Interests were defined speciously (see: “flypaper theory”), vaguely (see: “make clear to the world that we will not tolerate…”), and in aspirational terms irrelevant to the daily lives of the American people (see: “the expansion of freedom in all the world”). Colby makes the case that China, by contrast, threatens the substantive economic interests and liberal values of the American people in a way untested for generations, if ever. We have always been protected by two great oceans, but then we built an economic system that allows foreign powers to harm us from the comfort of home.

I find Colby’s definition of the problem compelling, and his proposed goal encouragingly concrete and attainable: “A favorable, stable, and enduring balance of power with China.” The goal does not itself resolve particular foreign policy questions—one could believe, as he does, that defending Taiwan is vital to achieving it, or one could make the case that drawing our red line on Taiwan’s other side is the better course. But the balance-of-power framework provides a means for interrogating the claims: Is the disagreement over the nature of our interests, the plausibility or necessity of preventing Chinese hegemony for protecting those interests, or the importance of defending Taiwan to achieving that goal? Questions like these will affect American families, communities, and industry, and the nation’s liberty and prosperity, in ways policymakers have failed so far to contemplate.

Oren Cass
Oren Cass is the executive director at American Compass.
@oren_cass
Recommended Reading
The Case for a Hard Break With China

In Foreign Affairs, Oren Cass and Gabriela Rodriguez make the case for why economic de-risking is ot Enough

Only Trump Could Confront China

The inside story of the trade negotiation that changed the world

Policy Brief: End “Permanent Normal Trade Relations” with China

Reclaiming control of U.S. trade policy

After Hegemony

Elbridge A. Colby November 19, 2021 - Globalization

America may no longer be the world’s dominant state, but we must not allow China to claim that title

RECOMMENDED READING
The Case for a Hard Break With China
Only Trump Could Confront China
Policy Brief: End “Permanent Normal Trade Relations” with China

For the last generation, one nation has wielded unmatched military power, bent the international financial system to its will, established almost unilaterally the standards of global communication and infrastructure, and dominated culture and media. For Americans, these seemed good years. And for most others, America’s tutelage was easy, its burden light—certainly compared to history’s other real or aspiring hegemons.

Those days have come to an end. China is the most formidable state Americans have dealt with certainly since the Soviet Union and in some ways since the 19th century. China’s economy is almost as large or perhaps larger than America’s already and, with roughly four times our population and an increasingly educated workforce, its overall (if not per capita) productive capacity should eventually exceed ours by a comfortable margin. By contrast, the Soviet Union, Nazi Germany, Imperial Japan, and Imperial Germany were all considerably smaller economies. China has also proved capable of succeeding in the global economy in a way that the Soviets never would or could. As a result, China has a lot of power to use on—and against—us and the things we care about.

“After decades of foreign policy debates centered on dealing with states and actors far weaker than ourselves, the United States has lost the “finger tip feel” and grammar for determining how to respond to a nation that is comparable to us in power.”

Indeed, recognition that China is a profound challenge is one of the few matters that draws forth near unanimity in American politics. While the Trump Administration was the first to adopt a more realistic and confrontational response to Beijing’s growing power and assertiveness, the Biden Administration has essentially continued its predecessor’s basic line, albeit in different form and fashion and with different areas of focus. The view that China poses a very serious challenge may be one of the few areas of genuine and meaningful bipartisan agreement in the Congress, and polls indicate that the American people themselves increasingly recognize China as a serious and primary threat.

But after decades of foreign policy debates centered on dealing with states and actors far weaker than ourselves, the United States has lost the “finger tip feel” and grammar for determining how to respond to a nation that is comparable to us in power. Why China is such a challenge and what we should try to do in counteracting it remain at best vaguely defined. In point of fact, the answers to these questions are far from obvious. After all, China is far away, as is Asia, where most of Beijing’s influence is currently felt. Meanwhile, America is physically secure, located behind two great oceans and protected by a large military and survivable nuclear arsenal. The chances of China invading and occupying the United States are therefore remote. Further, America is very rich. While our nation has serious problems, including social alienation and inequality, we are in relative terms doing well and our growth prospects emerging from the pandemic appear relatively good.

So, what, then, do we have to worry about? And what should we be trying to achieve?

* * *

In answering these questions in the context of such a powerful challenge, we need to start from first principles. As a republic of free and equal citizens, our interests are: first, our physical security; second, our freedom; and third, our prosperity. The promise of American life, in other words, depends on our being reasonably safe, free, and prosperous. Our interests in confronting China are precisely to protect these, especially our prosperity and, relatedly, our freedom.

It is of critical importance to our prosperity and ultimately our freedom that no state dominate one of the key market areas of the world. This sounds abstract and detached but, if allowed to happen, would be very real in its implications for Americans. A state that could exercise sway over a very large portion of the global economy could and almost certainly would use that enormous leverage to shape—really even determine—international economic flows, regulations, and trade to its benefit. Over time, this would make us increasingly dependent upon a foreign power and weaken our companies, our workers, and our economy.

The most plausible and consequential threat of that coming to pass is China’s attainment of hegemony over Asia. Asia comprises roughly half of the global market, and that share is rising. China constitutes roughly half of Asia’s GDP. If Beijing exercises control over Asia’s huge and growing market area, its influence will ultimately be dominant worldwide as well, giving it the market, scale, and regulatory power to define the world’s future. Building upon such economic advantages, it could intrude into and shape our national life, using its position to coerce, bribe, and cajole companies, individuals, and governments to do its will, diminishing our economic vitality and, through that, our freedoms.

“If Beijing exercises control over Asia’s huge and growing market area, its influence will ultimately be dominant worldwide as well, giving it the market, scale, and regulatory power to define the world’s future.”

We already see this happening around the world, as China brings its immense economic power to bear. The most famous example is the Belt and Road Initiative, a massive network of Chinese investments designed to net China closely with the countries of Eurasia through overland and maritime links, as well as the financial links that accompany those investments. This is giving China more leverage throughout the region, leverage it has increasingly put to use. To take just one example: When Sri Lanka failed to pay its heavy Belt and Road debts, China extracted a 99-year lease to a key port in the island country.

But China is not just picking on the small fry; rather, it is using its growing economic leverage to seek to coerce more advanced economies as well. For instance, it is currently trying to use its status as a major importer from Australia to compel that nation to submit to 14 searching and even humiliating demands, including changes to Australia’s domestic legislation and dampening of media coverage that is critical of China. The proximate cause of Beijing’s pressure is that Canberra had the audacity to call for an independent investigation of the origins of the COVID-19 virus. Beijing has also sought to its economic heft to coerce South Korea over missile defense deployments and Japan over territorial disputes in the East China Sea.

There is little reason to think that the United States would be spared such manipulation if China had the power to effect it. Indeed, we have already seen Chinese economic leverage marshalled against major American brands like Disney, the NBA, and Marriott—sadly, with some success. Even cage fighter John Cena, concerned for his movie’s success in China, was reduced to apologizing for inadequately toeing Beijing’s line on Taiwan.

This is just a taste of what China will do if it attains a hegemonic position over Asia. First and foremost, such a China would reshape international economic flows, regulation, and trade in its favor and to its preferences. This is a natural instinct of dominant states, as it provides great benefits on multiple levels. It allows the dominant state to ensure that the most lucrative and beneficial forms of economic activity cluster within and for itself rather than for others and somewhere else. It generates scale, enabling firms to gain advantages and compete more efficiently, thereby becoming more productive and dominant and making their investors, officers, and employees wealthier and more secure.

Think how the American-born internet supported Silicon Valley, and vice versa, leading to a World Wide Web governed by formal laws and informal norms almost entirely of American design. Think how the desire for access to American capital markets gives American regulators de facto control over global accounting standards, or how the need to transact with American institutions allows U.S. Treasury officials to freeze the assets of designated targets anywhere in the world. Think how Americans take for granted that English is the universal language and that everyone accepts dollars. Think how the American university degree has become the preeminent global academic credential, with searching implications for everything from global educational standards to measures of professional success.

“We have already seen Chinese economic leverage marshalled against major American brands like Disney, the NBA, and Marriott—sadly, with some success. Even cage fighter John Cena, concerned for his movie’s success in China, was reduced to apologizing for inadequately toeing Beijing’s line on Taiwan.”

Now think instead of the yuan as the reserve currency of the globe and the dollar supplanted, with China rather than the United States enjoying that “exorbitant privilege.” China’s central bank, not America’s, would set the global economy’s tempo. Think of China’s sanctions power equaling America’s today. Think of China dominating fractious and economically anemic Europe as well, with Beijing acting as gatekeeper and term-setter for access to the enormous market of Asian consumers. Standing alone in comparison to such a dominant China, America would no longer be the decisionmaker; it would have to conform to China’s preferences.

And forget lobbying Congress to change how social media companies are regulated; Americans would have to petition Chinese officials and regulators, with far less chance of accountability, let alone hope of success. Today’s internet has been decisively shaped by the United States, with its strong preference for open and broadly “liberal” ideas. Europe, meanwhile, focuses on privacy protections. Yet the People’s Republic of China values neither. Beijing represses speech on its own internet and allows little if any privacy protection. If China set the rules of the internet, Beijing would naturally tend to shape them in such directions. The same would go for everything from surveillance to speech controls to banking. It already uses technology, including facial recognition, big data, and artificial intelligence to impose and police so-called “social capital” scores for its own citizens. Why would famously nationalistic China treat foreigners more leniently?

“China could insist on labor, information, regulatory, environmental, and legal changes that decisively shaped Americans’ lives. The professional and probably much of the personal lives of Americans would be shaped—if not determined—by Chinese leaders.”

Instead of being the world’s great large economy, the pinnacle of mass prosperity, and the master of its own fate, America would become something much less. We would likely remain more prosperous than many countries, but we would live under China’s economic shadow. Chinese companies would gobble up or render dependent American—and European, Japanese, and South Korean—companies, leaving America’s economic fortunes to be decided upon in China. China could insist on labor, information, regulatory, environmental, and legal changes that decisively shaped Americans’ lives. The professional and probably much of the personal lives of Americans would be shaped—if not determined—by Chinese leaders.

Importantly, China need not create a great territorial empire to achieve this position of hegemony over Asia and, from there, a predominant global position. Rather, it simply needs to exert enough influence over the countries of the region with respect to their important economic and strategic decisions. A hegemonic China would not directly rule over countries within its sphere, but those countries would follow Beijing’s line on key economic, political, and military matters—or else. In practice, such subordinated states would orient their trade, economic, and regulatory policies to China’s demands, and avoid provoking Beijing by making or sustaining alliances or independent trading relationships with rivaling states—above all the United States.

* * *

How do we head off this outcome? Let’s first be clear about what we don’t need. We don’t need China to fundamentally change its internal system. We don’t need to dismember it. We don’t need it to bend the knee to us. We don’t need to establish our own hegemony over Asia. Such delusions led us to the sorry impasse in which we now find ourselves. What we do need is disciplined focus on what our enlightened interests specifically require.

Our goal should be a favorable, stable, and enduring balance of power with China. We want—in coalition with other states that share our interests—to agglomerate enough power that we can prevent China from undermining our prosperity and the liberty it enables. We want to reach a point at which we—along with our allies and partners in this balancing coalition—are strong enough that China, recognizing the futility of attempting serious coercion or violence against us, must respect our interests. Once we have attained such a position of strength, we can pursue détente with Beijing, but not before.

As a basic yardstick, we need a balancing coalition that is larger in GDP terms than China and its allies, probably by a decent measure given that China is a unitary giant of a state and thus can act more cohesively than a large coalition. That standard is a bit crude, but it captures the core idea: an effective balancing coalition needs to be a group of states whose “hard” economic and military power is greater with respect to the theater of focus than that of China’s own group. Think primarily of the United States, Japan, India, Australia, South Korea, Taiwan, some South and Southeast Asian states, and, less directly, some states from outside Asia. Europe can help, primarily by contributing economic scale and by taking care of its own security and that of its immediate neighborhood. But the core of this coalition will be in Asia.

“Our goal should be a favorable, stable, and enduring balance of power with China. We want—in coalition with other states that share our interests—to agglomerate enough power that we can prevent China from undermining our prosperity and the liberty it enables.”

If we can assemble and sustain such a group, we can blunt China’s aspirations to dominance. If Beijing tries economic coercion, our coalition will be able to make up losses by deeper economic connections amongst ourselves. If Beijing tries military force, our combined military power will be able to effectively defend the states China targets.

This standard achieved, Beijing will have to respect our interests, but it will still have immense power and a leading place in the international system, something in which the Chinese can take enormous pride. The downside is that China will remain a formidable threat. But the upside of drawing the limits of our strategy here outweigh this downside.

First, we can live with that China. We don’t need anything else from China for our security, freedom, and prosperity. We will retain plenty of market scale within our coalition and in the wide swath of countries likely to avoid affiliating with either us or Beijing.

Second, this standard will not require that we do anything to China. We won’t have to transform its government, dismember its territory, or establish our hegemony over it. This is critical because it will give China a compelling incentive for restraint—in other words, for Beijing to accept a stable balance, sufficiently content that the arrangement provides it enough security, dignity, and prosperity. We will need to confront China and push it hard to uphold the balancing coalition, but China will in any plausible future be hugely powerful, with a range of ways of gravely hurting us, from economic leverage through conventional military force all the way to a growing nuclear arsenal. We don’t want to push China so far into a corner that it judges lashing out too much with these instruments to be the best course.

By contrast, alternative strategies that insist we must democratize China or fundamentally weaken or collapse it would provoke far more cost and risk for Americans than is worthwhile. We might be better off with a democratic China—although that is not a given—just as we might be better off if we remained the only superpower. But thoroughgoing pursuit of those goals would trigger China to take drastic measures, with consequences far graver than the stakes are worth for us.

“Alternative strategies that insist we must democratize China or fundamentally weaken or collapse it would provoke far more cost and risk for Americans than is worthwhile.”

This doesn’t mean we should oppose a democratic China or swear off undermining the People’s Republic. To the contrary, we can and should support democratic government in China. Indeed, it already exists among the Chinese on Taiwan. And we will need to take steps to weaken China’s economic and military power to secure ourselves and our coalition partners. But we should only insist on these measures as needed to attain that favorable, stable, and enduring balance of power in Asia. We may hope for beyond that—for a free mainland China, for instance—but we should not force the issue.

* * *

It is important to underline, though, that the situation is urgent, because the key to preventing China’s attainment of regional hegemony over Asia is acting now. We need to blunt Beijing’s ambitions presently in Asia, rather than deferring the problem. The Pacific Ocean is huge, but consulting the map reminds us that most of it is empty. Outside the United States itself, the vast majority of the Pacific’s economic activity clusters on its western shores—Japan, South Korea, China itself, Southeast Asia. If we wait to meet China halfway it will already have subordinated this huge economic area, essentially winning before the struggle has even started.

The problem this creates is that we must muster resolve to stand up—and, if necessary, fight—for very distant stakes, 10,000 miles from our homeland. And it is even more acute because Beijing’s incentive is to pursue a classic “divide and conquer” strategy. Rather than precipitate a large struggle or war with a consolidated coalition, Beijing’s incentive is to pick any such balancing coalition apart, selectively pressuring or attacking vulnerable members, positioning each effort as not justifying a robust enough American response. The most pressing threat is to Taiwan, on which China has focused its military efforts for a generation while we have been distracted in the Middle East.[inlineref id=1][/inlineref] This is the very real and painful quandary we face.

Part of the solution is preparing the right kind of defense: economic resilience so countries can resist Beijing’s economic coercion, and military defenses that defeat China’s ability to subordinate targeted countries, including Taiwan, while minimizing the costs and risks to ourselves. But equally crucial is for Americans to understand why this is worthwhile, which in turn will harden our resolve for such a contest. And this, in turn, will be the best deterrent to Beijing precipitating such a conflict, as it will see that we and our partners in this balancing coalition have both the way and the will to defeat any such attempt.

It’s one thing to say we are in serious, long-term competition with China. It’s quite another to follow through on such a policy. Americans must wrestle with why we are confronting China and what our goal in doing so is. Too much of our national discussion now about competing with China is disconnected, abstract, and hortatory. It needs to be much more concrete and connected to Americans’ interests, and in any event focused and candid. Failing here risks a fundamental breakdown in the event we are put to the test with China. And that moment may arrive, and may arrive soon.

Elbridge A. Colby
Elbridge Colby is cofounder and principal of the Marathon Initiative. A former Pentagon official, he is the author of The Strategy of Denial: American Defense in an Age of Great Power Conflict (2021).
Recommended Reading
The Case for a Hard Break With China

In Foreign Affairs, Oren Cass and Gabriela Rodriguez make the case for why economic de-risking is ot Enough

Only Trump Could Confront China

The inside story of the trade negotiation that changed the world

Policy Brief: End “Permanent Normal Trade Relations” with China

Reclaiming control of U.S. trade policy

applearrow-cardsarrow-sharearrowcaret-downcloseemailfacebook-squarefacebookfooter-imghamburgerinstagram-squarelinkedin-squarelinkedinpauseplayprintspotifystitchertriangletwitter-squaretwitter